mirror of
https://github.com/nhammer514/textfiles-politics.git
synced 2024-12-25 07:19:31 -05:00
194 lines
9.4 KiB
Plaintext
194 lines
9.4 KiB
Plaintext
FREE TRADE VERSUS PROTECTIONISM
|
|
|
|
By RICHARD M. EBELING
|
|
|
|
A specter is haunting the economies of the world. It is the
|
|
specter of protectionism. In one country after the other,
|
|
cries are heard that international trade, rather than bringing
|
|
mutual prosperity, imposes economic hardship on some nations
|
|
so that others may gain. Trading practices among nations are
|
|
declared to be "unfair." Jobs are supposedly lost through
|
|
"cheap" imports flooding domestic markets. Balance of trade
|
|
deficits threaten the financial stability of not only third-
|
|
world countries, but the United States as well.
|
|
|
|
And the solutions proposed are the same everywhere: demands
|
|
are made for the imposition or stiffening of trade
|
|
restrictions--the raising of barriers in the path of trade
|
|
among nations. It is claimed that limitations on amounts of
|
|
foreign supplies entering the domestic market, through either
|
|
tariffs that make foreign goods more costly or quotas that
|
|
prohibit the quantities which may be imported, will increase
|
|
the market share of domestic companies as well as enhance
|
|
employment opportunities at home.
|
|
|
|
The reasoning seems straightforward and sensible. However, it
|
|
suffers from one handicap: It is dead wrong! When implemented,
|
|
protectionist policies bring economic harm, as well as lower
|
|
standards of living, for the people of every nation choosing
|
|
to follow this path.
|
|
|
|
If the protectionist argument is correct, that buying Japanese
|
|
goods, for example, is harmful to American industry and jobs
|
|
as a whole, then the same logic would have to imply that
|
|
importing New Mexico goods is harmful to Texas industry and
|
|
jobs; and that buying Fort Worth goods is harmful to Dallas
|
|
industry and jobs. Why does the Japanese-U.S. argument seem
|
|
plausible, while the Fort Worth-Dallas argument appears
|
|
suspect? Because people still suffer from the tribal notion
|
|
that suggests that the accident of a political boundary across
|
|
the face of a map must imply antagonism between the human
|
|
beings who live on different sides of that boundary.
|
|
|
|
International trade is nothing more than an extension of the
|
|
social division of labor across national borders. And the same
|
|
advantages that arise from a division of labor between members
|
|
of the same nation apply among members of different nations.
|
|
It enables a specialization of skills and abilities, with each
|
|
member of the world economic community tending to specialize
|
|
in that line of production in which he has a comparative
|
|
advantage (a relative superiority) in relation to his trading
|
|
neighbors.
|
|
|
|
Through such a division of tasks and activities, the wealth
|
|
and prosperity of every nation is increased, as compared to a
|
|
situation in which individuals or nations are required to
|
|
obtain what they desire through their own efforts, in economic
|
|
isolation from their fellow men.
|
|
|
|
But what of the particular charges presently leveled against
|
|
our foreign trading partners? What about the detrimental
|
|
effects which supposedly result from the trading policies of
|
|
other nations? Let us examine some of these charges:
|
|
|
|
1. Unfair Trading Practices. A number of nations have been
|
|
accused of unfairly subsidizing the export of goods to
|
|
America, i.e., at prices which are below their "actual" cost
|
|
of production.
|
|
|
|
The world is going through a dramatic technological and
|
|
economic revolution, with many underdeveloped nations finally
|
|
entering the industrialized era. Their lower prices often
|
|
merely reflect their lower costs of production, as they shift
|
|
into positions in the international division of labor which
|
|
reflect those areas where their relative economic efficiencies
|
|
are greatest. As these nations sell more in the United States,
|
|
they earn the purchasing power to buy more from America.
|
|
American exports, therefore, increase because the only way for
|
|
foreigners to buy more from Americans is for Americans to sell
|
|
more to foreigners.
|
|
|
|
To the extent that foreign governments do subsidize some
|
|
products sold in the U.S., this means that Americans are able
|
|
to buy them below what would have otherwise been the market
|
|
price. In other words, we are given a bargain, a bargain that
|
|
saves us resources that would have been devoted to the making
|
|
of more products to pay for what otherwise would have been
|
|
higher-priced imports. And these resources are now available
|
|
to make other things that we would not have been able to
|
|
produce without this bargain. It is the citizens of those
|
|
other nations who should be outraged since they, not us, have
|
|
to foot the tax bill to pay for the subsidies.
|
|
|
|
2. Foreign Products Cause Loss of Jobs. The charge is made
|
|
that the sale of foreign goods in America "steals" markets
|
|
away from American companies, with a resulting loss of jobs in
|
|
America.
|
|
|
|
This argument ignores the fact that these foreign goods must
|
|
be paid for. It is true that jobs in those sectors of the
|
|
economy which directly compete against certain foreign
|
|
products may be lost. But other jobs are created in those
|
|
industries which manufacture goods which foreigners are
|
|
interested in purchasing from Americans. The sale of foreign
|
|
goods in America may change the locale and types of
|
|
employments in the U.S., but it need not result, over time, in
|
|
any net loss of jobs.
|
|
|
|
Furthermore, with free trade, Americans end up spending less
|
|
of their income on certain products because they are bought
|
|
more cheaply from foreign suppliers. This leaves them with
|
|
extra dollars by which they are able to increase their demand
|
|
for other goods on the market. The net effect, therefore, is
|
|
to stimulate even more employment opportunities than
|
|
previously existed.
|
|
|
|
3. The Balance of Trade Deficit and Foreign Investment. The
|
|
leading issue during the last several years has been the
|
|
charge that America buys more abroad than it sells, resulting
|
|
in a trade deficit that threatens the economic stability of
|
|
the United States.
|
|
|
|
It is true that in terms of tangible or visible goods, the
|
|
U.S. has been buying more than it has sold. But this overlooks
|
|
the overall trade "balance sheet." Instead of buying American
|
|
commodities with the dollars they have earned, foreign earners
|
|
of dollars have returned some of them to America in the form
|
|
of savings in the credit markets, or as direct investment in
|
|
U.S. industry. The overall balance of payments between the
|
|
United States and the rest of the world has balanced.
|
|
|
|
When this is pointed out, the concern expressed is that
|
|
foreigners are "buying up America." "They" will control "us."
|
|
Actually, however, when the foreign investment is "indirect,"
|
|
i.e., loaned to Americans through the banking system, this
|
|
merely increases the pool of savings in the United States; and
|
|
this pool of savings is available to domestic businessmen who
|
|
desire to expand or improve their plant and equipment. If
|
|
wisely used, the money borrowed will be paid back, with
|
|
interest. And, in a few years, the productive capital in
|
|
America will be greater and more efficient. Industry will
|
|
still be in "our" hands.
|
|
|
|
But what if the investment is direct? Won't foreigners
|
|
"control" America by buying out existing companies or starting
|
|
up new businesses which successfully compete against American-
|
|
owned firms? Again, this reflects the collectivist notions of
|
|
past ages, notions which think of those who belong to other
|
|
nations--"tribes"--as inherently dangerous enemies.
|
|
|
|
But those of other nations who invest in America are actually
|
|
"our" captives--if one wishes to use this form of reasoning.
|
|
They have invested their savings in America because it has
|
|
offered the most attractive economic and political
|
|
environment. Their own fortunes and futures are linked to
|
|
continuing American prosperity; and they must manage their
|
|
investments in judicious, market-oriented directions if they
|
|
are to generate the profits for which they hope.
|
|
|
|
But what if "they" pulled out? Would that not hurt "us" by
|
|
disrupting "our" economy? In such a case, the physical plant
|
|
and equipment remain in America. To "pull out," they would
|
|
have to find willing buyers. And to do that, they would have
|
|
to offer attractive prices to prospective buyers. And they
|
|
would only want to sell out if either the political or
|
|
economic climate in the U.S. became less attractive as
|
|
compared to other countries. But are these not the same
|
|
incentives and motives which guide Americans who invest and
|
|
save in New York rather than California, or in the U.S. rather
|
|
than some other country?
|
|
|
|
While there will always be necessary adjustments to new and
|
|
changing circumstances, free trade between nations ultimately
|
|
benefits all who participate. Protectionism can only lead us
|
|
down a road of impoverishment and international commercial
|
|
tensions. To paraphrase the great 18th century, free-market
|
|
thinker, David Hume, when he criticized the protectionists of
|
|
his time: Not only as a man, but as an American, I pray for
|
|
the flourishing commerce of Germany, France, England and even
|
|
Japan. Why? Because America's prosperity and economic future
|
|
are dependent upon the economic prosperity of all of those
|
|
with whom it trades in the international division of labor.
|
|
|
|
Professor Ebeling is the Ludwig von Mises Professor of
|
|
Economics at Hillsdale College, Hillsdale, Michigan, and also
|
|
serves as vice-president of academic affairs for The Future of
|
|
Freedom Foundation, P.O. Box 9752, Denver, CO 80209.
|
|
|
|
------------------------------------------------------------
|
|
From the January 1991 issue of FREEDOM DAILY,
|
|
Copyright (c) 1991, The Future of Freedom Foundation,
|
|
PO Box 9752, Denver, Colorado 80209, 303-777-3588.
|
|
Permission granted to reprint; please give appropriate credit
|
|
and send one copy of reprinted material to the Foundation.
|